U.S. Intellectual History Blog

Some Thoughts on What Separates Working-Class History from the New History of Capitalism

Doris Day, in The Pajama Game, courtesy of LAWCHA

In a recent review for Dissent of three new books in working-class history, Gabe Winant writes movingly and incisively about the political education of the labor historians who elbowed their way into the profession between the 1960s and the 1980s.

It was precisely because they came from historically marginalized backgrounds and defended embattled traditions that these scholars—not just labor historians, but also women’s historians and African-American historians, collectively the “new social historians”—were positioned to pierce the fog of postwar historical complacency… In direct consequence of the professional struggle and advance of this cohort, the idea took hold as never before that American history was a history of dissent and resistance. The historical consciousness of past injustices and struggles that is visibly ascendant on today’s left—manifest, for example, in the conversation about reparations for slavery—owes a tremendous amount to this scholarship.

Winant’s review is in part a meditation on how labor history’s intellectual successes collided with the political disaster of organized labor, and of the difficulties that the field encountered and continues to encounter in adjusting the object of its analysis to account for transformations in what work looks like and who might be (or ought to be) included in the category “working class.” “The grounding of the field had lain in the social democratic state,” he writes, “which rested in turn upon the industrial economy and labor movement—widely seen as coterminous with labor history’s area of inquiry. As factories closed and the New Deal political regime disintegrated, the field began to lose its sense of a coherent project.”

Winant sympathetically describes labor history’s frustrations with its own inability to reassemble a synthesis that would truly encompass the U.S. working class as a whole—a project made even more improbable after the entry of transnational history on the scene and the eagerness of many younger labor historians to question the value and viability of the nation-state as the self-evident analytical container for the working class. But even before this challenge to the new labor history’s identity emerged, its practitioners were beginning to suspect that their hope for a new synthesis—an overarching frame in which all the hundreds of dissertations and monographs on the Worcesters and the Cincinnatis and the Lynns and the Lower East Sides could find their proper location—was not in the offing. “In the 1980s, the idea dawned that it might be impossible for the new social history to build a complete historical picture of the working class, brick by brick.”

Winant quietly seems to think that this dream of “a coherent project” or a “complete historical picture” was the right one, or at least that it may be more possible in the near future than it has been ever since the collapse of Fordism. He speculates that “we ought to expect that the reemergence of social conflict in the twenty-first century would bring with it a reimagined narrative of the working-class past, freed of some of the limits that constrained historians who struggled to see beyond the horizon set by midcentury social democracy.” Historians will be able to start picking up their bricks again—for one reason or another.

Embedded within Winant’s narrative, though, is a brief aside on the origins of the new history of capitalism, and it is worth—as part of my larger series here exploring the origins of the field—examining more closely. The new history of capitalism’s intellectual origins obviously do have a lot to do with the way the field of labor or working-class history was changing, and Winant’s account is a good example of how working-class historians think about that relation. (It is also more gracious and less acidic than some of the others that have been published recently.)

Winant argues that the new history of capitalism needs to be contextualized against the backdrop of “the high-neoliberal, end-of-history moment”—a statement which probably no one would argue with. But contextualization is not interpretation, and his conclusions about how budding historians of capitalism responded to neoliberalism are, I think, questionable. He imagines the budding historians of capitalism thinking to themselves,

Why study the working-class gravediggers of capitalism, when they had died out themselves before getting the job done? It was capitalism that was the survivor, and thus deserved attention. Only at this higher scale of analysis could phenomena like the historical ascent of finance and global trade be understood—newly important questions in the 1990s and 2000s.

It is a peculiar feature of the reactions to the new history of capitalism that economic historians think that the field’s center of gravity is in the antebellum period and labor historians place it in the 1980s, in both cases because that’s where they find the NHOC to be least self-critical and most enamored of its own novelty.

That aside, it seems less than fair to the first wave of historians of capitalism to portray them as such cold calculators, eager to side with the victors at the end of history. This is true especially when we consider that some bona fide labor historians were also becoming newly interested in “the historical ascent of finance and global trade” in these years. As an example, both Nelson Lichtenstein—whose labor credentials are impeccable—and Bethany Moreton wrote books about Wal-Mart at approximately the same time. They are significantly different books, and their differences are instructive in terms of understanding where the history of capitalism’s potential and distinctiveness lie. But is it reasonable to suggest that, because Moreton’s work was immediately associated with the history of capitalism, it was undertaken in a spirit of rejection for working-class history, or that Wal-Mart drew Moreton’s attention because its victories seemed more self-evidently important than the dissent and resistance of working people?

Winant certainly does not get so specific, and I don’t mean to put words in his mouth. But the overall frame of historians of capitalism as a group of scholars wanting to tell the history of the winners because they were the winners is not an uncommon attitude, despite the awkward fit it has with so many practitioners of the field and their work. Moreover, many studies from the new history of capitalism have attempted quite intentionally to expand our historical understanding of who counts as a part of the working class and to make the case for why our understanding of that category should change as a result. I’ll pick two from the antebellum period—Seth Rockman and Michael Zakim—and two from the post-Fordist economy—Moreton and Shane Hamilton.

Instead, it is possible that it is not the NHOC’s attitude to the working class per se that stands between the two fields, but rather its indifference to that hope for a “coherent project” or “complete historical picture” that has meant so much to labor history. There is very little in the new history of capitalism—even in its (innumerable) programmatic statements—that would suggest that its practitioners are interested in building a complete historical picture of American capitalism, “brick by brick.”

A great deal follows from this difference. Working-class history’s unfulfilled desire to write a total history of its subject comes out of a long history of struggle to bear adequate witness to the ephemeral rapture of solidarity. (Winant ends his review on a note of wistful solidarity.) In labor histories, the “plot” is usually oriented toward a culminating mass action, a moment of fusion and mutual sacrifice.

That is not usually the case in most histories of capitalism, and there is, I think, both an ideological and an archival reason for this. Certainly it is the case, as Winant points out, that the new history of capitalism is broadly liberal in the sense that its practitioners affirm as their “animating question” the problem of “how to live together in a society in which there is never just one story to tell.” Few histories of capitalism yet written encompass within their horizons a genuine expectation that capitalists as a class will cease to live among us; it is assumed that, even as capitalism is a historically contingent economic formation, historians will confront the continuing presence of both capitalists’ and workers’ stories for the foreseeable future. Thus, books in the new history of capitalism are often structured as either a series of chronologically parallel chapters (sometimes they are cases, but other times they are more like thematically connected scenes) or through the structuring metaphor of some kind of network or circuit. Edward Baptist’s innovative organization of The Half Has Never Been Told as a circuit around the body is an example that springs to mind, but William Cronon’s Nature’s Metropolis—an inspiration to many historians of capitalism—is also full of circuits.

Circuits are acts of coordination and articulation rather than rituals of solidarity, and there seems to be a pretty severe difference in the political subtexts and undertones that emanate from these two plot structures. Yet just as important, I think, as the ideological underpinnings that distinguish working-class history from the new history of capitalism are the practical archival problems and purposes that face the researcher. There are probably dozens of fine differences between the two, but I want to focus on one.

Historians of capitalism tend to (rightly) be careful in assuming and arguing for more class consciousness among their subjects than they can firmly prove. It is the privilege—otherwise known as the hegemony—of the ruling class that it does not have to be overtly class consciousness, and thus the archive presumably provides fewer direct expressions of capitalist class consciousness than does, say, a box of union grievances or a clutch of oral histories from workers. Even more, there are good reasons for capital to officially deny class consciousness in many of its forms, particularly in terms of coordination among capitalists. Some kinds of coordination are potentially illegal, and many others, if performed openly, would be unpopular. “The market” is a wonderful all-purpose mantle to throw over a whole variety of combinations.

The case of Nancy MacLean’s Democracy in Chains is a good example of what happens when a historian infers more coordination and deliberate intent than can be unshakably established by the evidence. While I believed at the time and continue to believe that her inferences were reasonable and convincing, her book was also open to objection that it lacked a “smocking gun.” It was perhaps her background in social/labor history—which I think tends to work from the assumption that class consciousness is always a factor in play—that got her into trouble here, rather than a lapse in standards. Libertarians are not, shall we say, so friendly to books that bake class consciousness into their arguments, and they were not likely to understand or to be charitable to a book that did.

The point, however, is that most new historians of capitalism tend to be more cautious than MacLean, or are working on projects where coordination can be explained at the institutional level—through a recognized lobbying group like NAM or through a specific firm—rather than in the fog of class consciousness. I think that this is a second major point of division between working-class history and the new history of capitalism, and perhaps of misunderstanding.

Whether that division can be bridged—or whether it should be—I don’t know. Perhaps the fields are complementary and needn’t be yanked and crushed into a single frame, a grand historical synthesis of economic life under capitalism. But then, again, as a scholar who identifies more with the historians of capitalism, of course I’d say that.

3 Thoughts on this Post

S-USIH Comment Policy

We ask that those who participate in the discussions generated in the Comments section do so with the same decorum as they would in any other academic setting or context. Since the USIH bloggers write under our real names, we would prefer that our commenters also identify themselves by their real name. As our primary goal is to stimulate and engage in fruitful and productive discussion, ad hominem attacks (personal or professional), unnecessary insults, and/or mean-spiritedness have no place in the USIH Blog’s Comments section. Therefore, we reserve the right to remove any comments that contain any of the above and/or are not intended to further the discussion of the topic of the post. We welcome suggestions for corrections to any of our posts. As the official blog of the Society of US Intellectual History, we hope to foster a diverse community of scholars and readers who engage with one another in discussions of US intellectual history, broadly understood.

  1. Hi Andrew,

    Thanks for the thoughtful and close reading. I really appreciate it, and it’s given me a lot to think about.

    I’d like to express a brief quibble with how you read me here, though — which I’m doing since I’ve heard multiple people express this, and have been surprised by it.

    My view is that placing a scholarly field in its historical context bears on its “loyalties” only in the most indirect way. To say that the history of capitalism is “about” the winners does not mean that it is “on the side of” the winners, at least in any straightforward way. One could, and I would (and it seems you would), lodge the criticism that it may unconsciously articulate a belief in capitalism’s permanence, but this can be the case regardless of its intent, which is quite explicitly the opposite. This is true for all historians: our efforts to mediate between our present moment and our past subject necessarily produce the past in the image of the present. It’s important to struggle against this inevitability, and that struggle itself is generative, but it is, axiomatically, an inevitability. This, for what it’s worth, is the inner tension that I find most compelling about history of capitalism: it’s an effort to historicize a phenomenon, which has arisen precisely because of the phenomenon’s ostensible apotheosis beyond the historical and into the apparently eternal, and so *must be* interpellated by the capitalism that it seeks to demystify. When capitalism seemed limited, there was much less concern to show that it was so; it is its new limitlessness that is what we are engaged in a dialogue with. (We could specify the material mechanisms of this interpellation, through funding and employment especially, though there are certainly other less precise, and probably more important, dimensions to it.) This is an intellectual trap, but it is no different than the kinds of intellectual traps we all fall into, all of us being historical subjects, and I think the best way to read much work in the field is as a negotiation with the constraints of this trap, rising at times to an escape attempt. This negotiation is just another name for what historians do.

    I also think this is what it means to place the field’s center of gravity in the 1980s: not that its central substantive focus is in the 1980s (there I’d agree that the nineteenth century has been much more important), but that its contextual specificity lies with the rise of neoliberalism.

    I agree that labor history is classically emplotted in a particular way—rising toward a moment of unity—and obviously it has a meta-plot as well, which was the subject of the piece: all those moments of unity themselves coalescing into the CIO. This directionality, ultimately a historiographical extension of the idea that the workers’ triumph is the logical endpoint of capitalism, proved disorienting after the defeat of social democracy and socialism in the 1970s and 1980s. And history of capitalism was offered as a way of dealing with this disorientation, by—as you say—dispensing with the directional logic in favor of the logic of circuitry. (This is nicely observed and put, I think.) But this is only to say that it does affirm capitalism’s timelessness, even as it explicitly disavows it! Whereas, to do labor history in the moment of ascendant neoliberalism meant working from a standpoint of limits to capital, even in a moment that gave no sign of them: quite a dilemma itself.

    This is why I think 2008-2016 has changed the dynamic, and probably made some kind of synthesis possible. History of capitalism represented an intellectual advance precisely because it was the historiographical manifestation of Marxists becoming willing to negotiate, much like Eric Hobsbawm backing New Labour; refusal on this count looked like it led to a dead end. But the historical cycle from 1980 that framed this transformation is over! What that means precisely is anybody’s guess, of course, but the limitless apotheosis of liberal capitalism is no longer that with which we must deal.

    • Hi Gabe,
      Thanks so much for your comment, and I appreciate the distinction you draw between being “about” the winners and “on the side of” the winners. I feel like where we might both be getting caught is in the unspoken acknowledgment that decisions about what to study are seldom taken without regard to career prospects, prestige, etc. I feel–and maybe I’m wrong here–that among labor historians there can be a sentiment that historians of capitalism are in some manner more careerist. The non-site essay I linked to above by Thomas Jessen Adams goes in that direction a bit, I feel.

      I understand much better–and agree with you–about the reasons why you think the 1980s acts as the field’s center of gravity. But I feel that we also need to acknowledge the importance of the anti-globalization movement in the political education of many historians of capitalism, and therefore locate at least part of the field’s reluctance to think of capitalism as limited as a product of the 1990s–of free trade and the promise of the internet (as preached by Wired and others). To me, the field’s investment in the 1980s seems to be its gravitation toward finance rather than its overall conceptualization of capitalism. The 1980s give the field a direction, but the 1990s gave it its momentum.

      Maybe? I’m just thinking this out for the first time, more or less.

  2. I agree with Andrew (if I read him correctly) that the disorientation came not from the defeat of social democracy but from the recasting of global capitalism in recent decades, hence HoC’s shift from labor to political economy as an analytical framework. In this sense, the “endpoint” that defined the genre of labor history (and became more and more untenable) was not the necessary triumph of workers but industrial capitalism as the culmination of “modernization.”
    This is what troubled me about the piece in Dissent: we need to be much more cautious about falling back to a new stage theory of history: evolutionary phases that inexorably unfold. But Gabe’s observations about the timelessness of capitalism are, of course, incredibly perceptive and important (see also Sklansky on this point). What is ultimately the best way out of this impasse? I think it has to be work that engages broadly with political economy but takes class politics much more seriously as historically formative.

Comments are closed.